Is There Inflation in Our Future?
Below is another article from the Global Economic Intersection and from author Gene Balas. This article answers in detail whether or not there is inflation in our future. The analysis is thorough and covers both the monetary issues and the issues that drive inflation at the business and consumer levels. Once again I encourage you to visit the Global Economic Intersection. It has some good stuff.
The article is in italics and the bold is mine. From GEI:
We
see a few signs of budding inflation. But will it bloom? Survey data
point to businesses’ higher costs in recent months. The key question is whether those cost
increases are temporary or persistent, and whether they will be passed on to
their customers in higher prices. That, in turn, depends on the cause.
Let’s take a closer look. We do see signs of increasing cost
pressures in both the goods and the services sectors, in data from the
Institute for Supply Management.
Manufacturers
reported paying higher prices recently, and the trend is moving up a bit.
The ISM-Manufacturing Prices Index
registered 58 in September, which is an increase of 4 points
compared to August, and follows a 14.5 point increase in August compared to
July. In June, it printed 37.0. Readings above “50” indicates more
businesses than fewer are reporting higher input costs. In September, 27% of
respondents reported paying higher prices, 11% reported paying lower prices,
and 62% of supply executives reported paying the same prices as in August.
They seem to be passing along some of those price increases to
their customers. The ISM-Non Manufacturing Survey, which includes
retailers and wholesalers, among other services industries, shows even more
cost pressures. ISM’s Non-Manufacturing Prices Index for September registered
68.1, an increase of 3.8 points from the 64.3 percent reported in
August. It is considerably higher than the 48.9 in June. In September,
28% of respondents reported paying higher prices, 71% indicated no change in
prices paid is 71%, and 1% of the respondents reported lower prices.
If these price increases are seen as persistent, rather than
transitory, will they pass on those higher costs to their customers?
Here’s what the Atlanta Fed recently reported on a study of firms that were
presented with a hypothetical increase in their costs by either 2% or 6%, with
the goal of finding out pricing power and cost pass-through to the end
customer:
On average, firms faced with the 2 percent cost increase were
likely to pass about 1.3 percentage points (or 66 percent) to their customers.
In the portion of our panel considering the 6 percent cost increase, the
average impact on customer prices was 3.8 percentage points (or about 63
percent of the cost increase). So in the aggregate, firms think they can pass
about two-thirds of any cost increase through to prices, and that belief holds
roughly true whether the cost increase is relatively modest or somewhat large.
So,
we see that businesses are reporting that their costs are going up, and that
they believe they can pass along much of those cost increases. (The difference,
of course, would be reflected in reduced profit margins.) How do
businesses see these costs, as something to pass along – which can hurt sales,
if customers switch to a competitor – or to absorb perhaps temporary cost
increases to maintain market share? The answer is what is perceived as the
cause, and how long that condition is perceived to last.
What
many observers might blame, rightly or wrongly, are the actions of the
Fed. In the minds of many observers is the monetarist view of inflation,
and some may say something to the effect of, “All that money the Fed is
‘printing’ will cause prices to rise. Inflation is a monetary
phenomenon.” Many people equate QE with an expansionary monetary
policy. But is that really true with the Fed’s quantitative easing
programs? Or, are other factors instead more of a concern?
Let’s put to rest that notion that QE directly causes inflation. As many
investors, if not the general public, recognize, the Fed’s asset purchases
aren’t intended to expand money in circulation, but instead to bring down
longer term interest rates through longer duration bond purchases. (M2
money supply has grown 6.3% in the year to August, mostly in the form of
savings deposits.)
Here’s
what happens when the Fed buys financial assets, whether they be Treasury bonds
or mortgage instruments. The party, perhaps an institutional investor or
a financial institution, that receives the cash from the Fed then takes those
proceeds and buys another investment security. Some of those funds could
be used for new loans, if both borrower and lender alike are willing and able
to transact.
Unless
it is lent out, where is the cash? It is held all along in the banking system,
parked right back at the Federal Reserve, in the form of banks’ “excess
reserves,” where it currently earns 0.25% interest. Those monies were
never “printed,” because they haven’t left the financial system.
The
only way those funds can become inflationary is if they leave banks’ excess
reserves. One way might be if perhaps a person sells a security to the
Fed, receives the cash and buys, say, a car. However, there is little reason to
think people are buying toasters with funds they receive by selling bonds to
the Fed. The savings rate is still positive, meaning the Fed’s purchases
are not being used by consumers for shopping sprees as consumers are still
adding financial assets to their balance sheets, not selling them.
Instead,
the biggest way those funds can become inflationary is if banks start making
substantial new loans from those excess reserves. Right now, we see that
data from the FDIC shows that loan growth in the 12 months through June was
2.7%, aggregated among all bank loan types. Over the past two years, loan
growth totaled just 1.6% – and that is not an annualized figure.
Aggregate loan growth so far is tepid, especially compared to nominal GDP
growth, which was 3.9% year-over-year to the second quarter 2012. (Loan data
are not adjusted for inflation, hence the use of nominal GDP.)
With income
growth stagnant and
many people not quite creditworthy, banks might not find many suitable
customers. That may keep supply of credit low, at the same time demand to
borrow funds is similarly restrained.
Consumers
are more focused on paying down debt than they are in taking out more loans,
except for two categories: auto and student loans. Consumers have been
buying more cars, most likely because the average age of cars on the road is at
a record high. Unemployed workers may take out student loans to upgrade their
skills to find a job. Combined, the category of non-revolving loans that
includes this debt rose by 5% so far in 2012 and is up 22% from 2008.
However, credit card debt hasn’t grown by much since the end of
2011, and is 17% less than its 2008 peak. Outside of cars, banks don’t
appear to be granting loans to fuel consumer spending, especially for unsecured
credit products. Thus, unless both banks and consumers change their view
of consumer debt, spending gains here will need to come primarily from income
or savings. See Steve Hansen’s report today for the latest
consumer credit data.
Businesses
aren’t borrowing as much, either. Big corporations have a treasure trove of
just over a trillion dollars in cash, and hardly need to borrow. (And I
might also add this might keep supply of new corporate bonds less than what it
would be otherwise.)
Meanwhile, the National Federation of Independent Businesses
reports more than half of small businesses explicitly stated in the group’s
survey that they do not want a new loan. Thus, even if banks were
willing to lend, their potential customers are not enthused to borrow. So
those funds in excess reserves are lying fallow.
Perhaps
at some point those reserves might get lent. However, should the economy
show signs of any inflationary pressures, the Fed can take action to reduce the
economy’s inflationary potential. Besides actually selling bonds in the
open market or hiking the Fed Funds rate, the Fed can simply, and quite easily,
increase the interest rate it pays on those excess reserves. This reduces the
incentive for a bank to lend funds to Sally to buy a car when it can earn
risk-free interest from the Federal Reserve.
That
said, investors can take the proceeds from selling bonds to the Fed and invest
them into other assets, like stocks or commodities. In that vein, we must
consider the extent to which QE could trigger commodity price spikes. That is a
concern, but recently, however, commodity prices have been coming down.
Additionally, commodities and basic material inputs tend to be a small
component of the final price of a good or service.
An
intervening factor is currencies. A stronger dollar compared the euro
from weakness in Europe would tend to keep commodity prices lower, as many
commodities are priced in dollars. A stronger dollar(vs. what it would be
otherwise) means more expensive oil in Europe, all things equal, and that means
relatively lower commodity prices as global traders tend not to bid up prices
as much. Overall, the U.S. dollar index against a basket of currencies is
little changed from a year ago, though has bounced around a bit in between.
And
a stronger dollar relative to what it would be otherwise can keep inflation in
the U.S. under control by making imported goods cheaper. So far,
quantitative easing hasn’t prompted the amount of dollar weakness that some had
forecast, again, because it is not intended to increase money supply.
That means inflation from imports is tame, decreasing 2.2% over the past
year. Of course, when the Fed is a ready buyer of bonds, it may give
foreign investors greater confidence to maintain their own purchases.
Considering all of these factors, consumers, businesses and
investors aren’t expecting increases in certain inputs or commodity prices
(gas, food, etc.) to be long lasting. These prices have a way of bouncing
around that don’t always affect expectations over the long run, say more than
five years or so. And indeed, inflation expectations have been
contained. Expectations have probably been influenced by the inflation
experienced in the past couple of years with CPI fluctuating above and below 2.5% and PPI declining sharplyfrom above 7% to approaching 0%
for finished goods and actually deflating in 2012 for crude materials after
inflating at double digit rates in 2011.
In the Consumer Confidence Survey from The Conference Board, consumers’
inflation expectations have remained stable, even dropping a bit to 3.3% from
3.6%, for the next 12 months. Investors’ inflation expectations, per the
TIPS breakeven rates, are also stable, have been in the range of about 2.2% to
2.4%, though they spiked higher (and then retreated) immediately following the
announcement of QE3. The Atlanta Fed reports that businesses have
expected inflation to be between 1.5% and 2.0% in a remarkably stable range over
the past year.
Inflation expectations
often tend to lead actual inflation, as the expectation of higher prices tends
to be a self-fulfilling prophecy. Quite simply, people are more willing to pay
higher prices when they expect them to be as such. Workers are more
likely to demand higher wages when they expect their expenses to climb. Wages
are a bit different from other cost inputs for a company, however.
In
contrast to commodity prices, wages tend to make up around two-thirds of the
cost of goods and services, economy-wide. And also unlike commodity
prices, which can rise and fall on a daily basis, wages are sticky.
Companies cannot change workers’ salaries the same way the crude oil trades in
the commodities pits. Thus, employers will think twice about granting pay
raises, and for the time being, companies in most (though not all) industries
are able to avoid doling out more money to their staff.
High
unemployment means more competition for jobs and smaller pay raises, and this
limits companies’ cost components. Fewer pay raises means less demand for
goods and services, and this means less ability to pass along higher prices.
Low wage growth, for both the cost and revenue side of companies’ income
statements, argues for continued lower inflation and interest rates.
Thus,
this thesis of resource slack is one of the competing theories for whether
inflation will become problem. Monitoring how much slack in the economy –
particularly for labor – is perhaps key to determining when inflation from
rising wages might take hold.
What do we see right now for resource slack? The Atlanta Fed polled businesses and found that, on average, companies
say their current sales are about 8% below what they say is a “normal”
level. However, business’ industry matters. Sectors in services are
seeing a different pattern than goods-producing sectors.
Retailers, for example, say their current sales are a
little less than 2% below normal. And firms in the leisure/hospitality and the
transportation/warehousing sectors say they are operating at, or just a shade
above, normal levels. Not coincidentally, job growth in these services
sectors has been strong in recent months, outpacing overall job growth.
In food services alone, the job growth rate has been double total job
growth since the end of 2009. Wage increases could occur in these often
low-wage, labor intensive industries.
On the other hand, durable
goods manufacturers report
that their current sales levels are nearly 12% below normal, and finance and
insurance companies say their sales are almost 17% below normal. Housing
is a long ways off – construction firms are 28% under capacity according to the
Atlanta Fed’s survey. Thus, even if the Fed’s moves to lower rates
triggers more housing construction, there is scant pressure to grant wide-scale
pay increases there. Some manufacturing companies, though, report some
difficulty in finding talent with the right technical backgrounds, so certain
occupations may see rising wages here.
Without rising incomes, whether or not companies
believe that they can increase prices acting individually, consumer spending
cannot support spending in volume terms at current levels if all companies
increase prices, in aggregate. Thus, there is a limit to pricing power
when one views the economy as a whole instead of individual companies.
That said, more consumers are expecting their incomes to
increase. The proportion of those expecting that outcome rose to 16.3% in
the latest Consumer
Confidence Survey from
The Conference Board, up from 16.0% last month, reaching the highest level of
the year.
However,
until and unless pay raises actually become a reality – and that might be less
likely until the supply of labor is more balanced with the demand – then it is
hard to expect substantial inflation. Consumers’ response to rising
prices will be to purchase fewer goods and services, which then begs the
question of whether price increases would stick.
In
the meantime, since inflation expectations are generally stable and low, the
Fed to continue its easy money policies. Should those expectations
increase, the Fed can moderate its stance before those expectations become
reality. I believe that slack in the economy is the driving force keeping
inflation suppressed, while QE is not, in itself, inflationary.